Welfare Reducing Trade and Optimal Trade Policy
نویسندگان
چکیده
This paper shows that free trade reduces the welfare of a small country with unemployment unless the free trade price if the importable falls below the autarky equivalent price. A decline in the price of the importable from the autarky level not only improves the terms of trade but also reduces employment and production in the importable sector. A numerical example illustrates that the autarky equivalent price of the importable can be substantially lower than the autarky price. If an optimal tariff is used, however, restricted trade improves welfare above the autarky level. WELFARE REDUCING TRADE AND OPTIMAL TRADE POLICY Introduction Trade theorists have long believed that free trade necessarily improves the welfare of a small country. In a brilliant paper Kemp (1968, p. 158) suggested the possibility of a paradox that an improvement in the terms of trade results in a welfare loss. Johnson (1965) further argued that with factor price rigidity free trade may actually reduce the welfare of a small open economy, a special case of the Kemp paradox. Batra and Pattanaik (1970), however, demonstrate that even in the presence of factor price rigidity and factor immobility, free trade still dominates autarky because “production gain” is zero but “consumption gain” is positive, and further suggest that the possibility of a negative optimal tariff cannot be ruled out a priori. The possibility of welfare reducing trade has since been largely discounted and treated only as a theoretical curiosity. Due to a growing recognition that foreign imports are the cause of high unemployment, however, the protectionist mood has been spreading in the United States. The literature has also begun to investigate the link between unemployment and trade. Specifically, Batra and Beladi (1990) investigated the impacts of unemployment on the pattern of trade, citing widespread unemployment even in developed countries such as the United Kingdom and the United States in the 1930s as well as in the 1980s. In many countries the minimum wage is considered to be set by institutional arrangements such as unions or minimum wage legislations. Chao and Yu (1990) showed that an improvement in the terms of trade need not raise welfare of an economy suffering from urban unemployment. If imports of less expensive foreign goods are to raise domestic unemployment, some trade restrictions might prove beneficial. Batra (1992) also suggested that a movement towards freer trade in America led to productivity slowdown and lower real wages since 1972, and hence for the vast majority of people whose main income comes from labor earnings, freer trade generated increased poverty in the United States. This paper formulates a disequilibrium trade model with sticky money wages that has been generalized to fix-price economies where output prices as well as wages are fixed, independent of excess demand or supply in the labor and goods markets. This paper differs from existing literature in two important respects. First, unlike the models that only suggest the possibility of welfare reducing trade, this paper demonstrates that a decline in the price of the importable from the autarky level caused by free trade will necessarily reduce the welfare of a small country with unemployment. With unemployment, the economy can enjoy consumption gain from free trade, but production gain may become negative so that it outweighs any consumption gain. That is, the Kemp paradox necessarily occurs in the neighborhood of autarky. To demonstrate this result, we assume à la Batra and Beladi (1990) and Yu (1982) that only wage is rigid, permitting interest rate flexibility. Second, we construct a numerical example to illustrate that even if the free trade price of the importable falls substantially below the autarky level, a small country with unemployment may not recover from the negative welfare shock from the increase in unemployment. It is noteworthy that the amount of labor employed changes with the relative commodity price as a result of inequality between the marginal rate of transformation in production and the relative commodity price. As the price of the importable declines, welfare begins to improve beyond a certain point. When the price of the importable falls to the autarky equivalent price, the positive terms of trade effect exactly offsets the negative welfare effect of increased unemployment. Hence, this paper attempts to formally identify situations where tariff serves as an employment-protecting device. A numerical example illustrates a case where free trade does not improve welfare until the price of the importable declines to 50 percent of the autarky level. We also examine in this case whether autarky should be maintained, or a nonprohibitive import tariff should be used to offset the adverse welfare effect of opening trade. After describing the model and its solution, we discuss the implications of changing tariff rates on the foreign products. We then construct a numerical example to show that our result is a possibility for many countries with unemployment, then analyze the issues of optimal tariff. We conclude with some general remarks. Fixed Money Wage and Welfare Reducing Trade A small open economy with unemployed resources operates inside its production possibility frontier. Unemployment arises from imperfections in the factor markets. Harberler (1950), Johnson (1965), and Jones and Norman (1979) asserted that wages tend to be rigid due to institutional limitations. In The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money Keynes (1935, p. 268) argued that if money wages are inflexible “the greatest practicable fairness will be maintained between labor and the factors whose remuneration is contractually fixed in terms of money, in particular the rentier class and persons with fixed salaries.” Keynes further argued that while wage flexibility expedites resource transfers between industries, “money wage level as a whole should be maintained as stable as possible, at any rate in the short period” (p. 270). On the other hand, Keynes believed that interest rate is flexible, albeit he was uncertain about the effectiveness of monetary policy to control interest rate. For these reasons we consider a Keynesian open economy with fixed money wage and flexible interest rate to investigate the welfare effect of free trade and optimal trade policies. To lay the basis for analyzing the welfare effects of free trade for a small country with money wage rigidity, we adapt Batra and Beladi (1990) and Jones and Norman (1979) with the following assumptions: (i) The domestic economy consists of N identical consumers. (ii) Two factors, capital K and labor L, are used to produce two goods, the exportable z and the importable y. (iii) The exportable is the numeraire, and the domestic price q and the foreign price q* of the exportable are equal to unity. The economy is small and the foreign price of the importable p* is exogenous. (iv) In the short run the domestic wage w is rigid and does not respond to random changes in the domestic and foreign prices. Capital is fully employed, and mobile between sectors. The interest rate r is flexible and responds to price changes. (v) Perfect competition prevails in product markets and the capital market. Let Z and Y denote the domestic production of the exportable z and the importable y. Outputs of the traded goods are given by Z = F(Lz,Kz), Y = G(Ly,Ky), and the production functions F(@) and G(@) are assumed to be concave in inputs, where Li and Ki denote labor and capital employed in sector i, i = z,y. Producers in the export sector choose Lz and Kz to maximize profits, Bz = qF(Lz,Kz) wLz rKz. (1) The first-order conditions are: qFL w = 0, qFK r = 0, (1N) where q = q* = 1, and the subscripts denote partial derivatives. Similarly, producers in the import sector choose Ly and Ky to maximize profits, By = pG(Ly,Ky) wLy rKy, (2) The first-order conditions are: pGL w = 0, pGK r = 0. (2N) It is important to note that an increase in the price of one product does not directly affect factor demands in the other sector. However, an increase in the price of the importable affects the demand for capital in that sector and increases the interest rate. Thus, an increase in the price of the importable affects labor demand in the export sector indirectly via a change in interest rate. The input demand functions can be written Lz = Lz(q,w,r), Kz = Kz(q,w,r), Ly = Ly(p,w,r), Ky = Ky(p,w,r). Consumer preferences are represented by a monotone increasing utility function, U = U(C,X), where C denotes domestic consumption of the exportable and X denotes domestic consumption of the importable. The budget constraint of the consumer is C + pX = I, where I is income in terms of the numeraire good. The first-order condition is: UX/UC = p. Let C = C(p,I) and X = X(p,I) denote the demand functions for C and X. Then the indirect utility function is written V(p,I) / U[C(p,I),X(p,I)]. To reduce domestic unemployment the government restricts trade by imposing a tariff t = p ! p* on imports. The import demand function is Q(p,I) = X(p,I) ! Y(p), (3) which implies QI = XI. The government revenue from trade taxes is g = (p ! p*)Q. (4) Following the convention, the tariff revenue is rebated to consumers. The aggregate profit, B = Bz + By , is returned to consumers as dividends. In addition to profit dividend, B, and tariff rebate, (p p*)Q, consumers also receive income from the sale of factor services. The consumer receives w(Lz + Ly) + r(Kz + Ky) from the factor markets. Hence, consumer income is I = F(Lz,Kz) + pG(Ly,Ky) + (p p*)Q. (5) Unemployment and Foreign Price of the Importable How does free trade affect the welfare of a small country with unemployed resources? To put it differently, if a small country adopts a free trade policy (p = p*), how does a change in the foreign price of the importable affect unemployment? Free trade necessarily results in a decrease in the price of the importable below the autarky level, at least in the two-good world. An increase (decrease) in the price of the importable encourages (discourages) domestic production of the importable. If the economy is operating along the production possibility frontier, the expanding import sector must attract resources from the other sector, and hence an increase in the foreign price of the importable necessarily reduces the domestic supply of the exportable. If both factors are not fully employed, increased production of the importable can be obtained by utilizing unemployed resources without contracting the export sector. However, when labor is unemployed and capital is fully employed, a change in the price of the importable affects the production of the exportable indirectly via a change in the interest rate. We first focus on the direct effect. For a given interest rate, an improvement in the terms of trade caused by a decline in p* does not affect employment or production in the export sector; i.e., MLz/Mp = MKz/Mp = MZ/Mp = 0. (6) However, we show that a decline in the import price reduces employment of normal factors in the import sector. From the first-order conditions in (2N), MLy/Mp = (GKGKL ! GLGKK)/p), (7a) MKy/Mp = (GLGKL ! GKGLL)/p), (7b) MY/Mp = GL(MLy/Mp) + GK(MKy/Mp) > 0, (7c) where ) / GLLGKK ! (GKL) > 0 by concavity of the production function, and (MY/Mp) > 0 by convexity of the cost function. Consider the cost minimization problem to produce a given output ?Y, and let Lz (?Y,w,r) and Kz(?Y,w,r) be the cost minimizing levels of inputs to produce ?Y. Assume that both labor and capital are strictly normal factors in industry y; i.e., dLy/d?Y > 0 and dKy/d?Y > 0. It can be shown that labor is a normal input if GKGKL ! GLGKK > 0. Similarly, capital is a normal input if GLGKL ! GKGLL > 0). Thus, if K and L are normal inputs, then MLy/Mp > 0 and MKy/Mp > 0. How does a decline in the foreign price of the importable affect domestic unemployment? Let L = Lz + Ly denote the aggregate demand for labor, and Lu = !L L denote the labor unemployment. Recall that MLz/Mp = 0 and MLy/Mp > 0, and hence MLu/Mp < 0. Thus, for a given interest rate, an increase in p increases aggregate demand for labor and reduces unemployment. Unemployment and Welfare Reducing Trade Observe that an indirect utility, V(p*,Z + p*Y), is inversely related to p* but positively related with national income, Z + p*Y. Thus, a decline in the price of the importable affects welfare in two opposite directions; the terms of trade effect on welfare is positive, but the income effect is negative. We show that unless the price of the importable falls below the autarky equivalent price the negative income effect dominates the terms of trade effect. Consider how national welfare is affected by a fall in the foreign price of the importable. If p = p*, the expression for national income in (5) reduces to I = Z + p*Y. Recall from (1N) that an increase in the price the importable does not directly affect the output of the export sector, but indirectly via a change in the interest rate. How does an increase in r affect the factor demands and output in the export sector? Differentiating (1N) yields MLz/Mr = FKL/qL, (8a) MKz/Mr = FLL/qL, (8b) where L / FLLFKK (FKL) > 0 by concavity of production function F(@). Differentiating Z with respect to r gives MZ/Mr = FL(MLz/Mr) + FK(MKz/Mr) = (FKFLL FLFKL)/qL. Using a cost minimization problem for a given output, it can be shown that FK FL(FKL/FLL) is positive (negative) if K is a normal (an inferior) factor. Thus, MZ/Mr is negative (positive) if K is a normal (inferior) factor. Equilibrium in the domestic capital market is given by Kz(q,w,r) + Ky(p,w,r) = !K. (9) Equation (9) defines how the equilibrium interest rate r(p) responds to a change in p. Differentiating (9) with respect to p gives dr/dp = (MKy/Mp)/[MKz/Mr + MKy/Mr]. (10) Recall from (7b) that MKy/Mp > 0 if K is a normal input. Thus, if K is a normal input, an increase in the price of the importable increases demand for capital and raises the interest rate, dr/dp > 0. Observe that dI/dp* = Y + p*(dY/dp*) + dZ/dp* = Y + w(dLy/dp*) + r(dKy/dp*) + w(dLz/dp*) + r(dKz/dp*) = Y + w(dL/dp*), (11) where L = Lz + Ly is aggregate demand, L < !L, and dKy/dp* + dKz/dp* = 0 since capital is fully employed. An increase in p not only affects the labor demand in the import sector for a given interest rate (direct effect), but also affects it indirectly by raising the interest rate. Thus, the total effects on labor demands can be written dLz/dp = (MLz/Mr)(dr/dp), dLy/dp = (MLy/Mp) + (MLy/Mr)(dr/dp). From (8a), MLz/Mr < (>) 0 if K and L are complements (substitutes) in the production of Z. Similarly, MLy/Mr < (>) 0 if K and L are complements (substitutes) in the production of Y. Thus, if K and L are complements (substitutes), the indirect effects, (MLi/Mr)(dr/dp), are negative (positive), i = y,z. If K and L are substitutes, then dLi/dp > 0, but the sign of dL/dp* = (MLz/Mr)(dr/dp) + (MLy/Mr)(dr/dp) + (MLy/Mp) is indeterminate if K and L are complements. However, the direct effects are likely to more than offset the indirect effects. Hereafter, we assume that an increase in the price of the importable increases aggregate demand for labor, dL/dp* > 0. Differentiating V(p*,Z + p*Y) with respect to p* and using Roy's identity, Vp = VIX, and (11) gives dV/dp* = VI[Q + w(dL/dp*)], (12) which is generally indeterminate. When evaluated at the autarky price p, Q = 0, and hence dV/dp* = VI@w(dL/dp*)> 0. That is, the initial welfare impact of opening up trade depends on the employment effect. Proposition I: Assume that money wage is fixed and interest rate is flexible. If dL/dp* > 0, then a decline in the price of the importable from the autarky level initially reduces welfare of a small country. Observe that if labor is fully employed, dL/dp* = d!L/dp* = 0 in (12), and dV/dp* = VIQ. In this case, Q > (<) 0 and dV/dp* < (>) 0 for p < (>) p*. Thus, indirect utility is minimized at the autarky price. However, when labor is unemployed, a minimum of indirect utility occurs at a price somewhere below the autarky price, p. A Numerical Example We have shown that there is a price interval in which a small open economy with unemployment loses from free trade. There is an autarky equivalent price p at which the small country is just as well off as under autarky; i.e., V(p,Z + pY) = V(p,Z + pY). If the foreign price of the importable falls below the autarky equivalent price (p* < p), the terms of trade effect dominates the negative income effect and the country gains from free trade, despite its adverse impact on unemployment. We now construct a concrete example to illustrate that the price of the importable may have to fall substantially below the autarky price for free trade to improve the welfare of a small open economy with unemployment. Consider a utility function U(C,X) = CX, which yields equal output shares in autarky. Demand functions are given by C = I/2 and X = I/2p, where I = Z + p*Y is consumer income under free trade. The indirect utility is V = I/4p = [Z + p*Y]/4p*. (13) The import demand function is Q = I/2p* Y. Recall that if p* = p, then Q = 0. Thus, p satisfies
منابع مشابه
Relationship between Economic Growth, Urban Concentration and Trade: Evidence from the Asia-Pacific
There is a significant relationship between economic growth and the degree of urban concentration, as measured by primacy or the share of the largest city in an urban system. In accordance to urban economic theories, there is an inverse-U shape relationship between urban concentration âurban primacy- and economic growth. That is, as economy grows, urban concentration increases, approaches a...
متن کاملOptimal replenishment and credit policy in supply chain inventory model under two levels of trade credit with time- and credit-sensitive demand involving default risk
Traditional supply chain inventory modes with trade credit usually only assumed that the up-stream suppliers offered the down-stream retailers a fixed credit period. However, in practice the retailers will also provide a credit period to customers to promote the market competition. In this paper, we formulate an optimal supply chain inventory model under two levels of trade credit policy with d...
متن کاملTrade and environmental distortions: coordinated intervention
Free trade may not improve welfare when environmental distortions exist. We study the coordination of trade and environmental policies when the distortion is loose property rights governing resources. Using the dual approach of Dixit and Norman (1980), we trade out ‘iso-welfare’ curves in the space of the degree of environment distortion and the level of the import tariff. We use these curves t...
متن کاملA Note on: Alternative Quantitative Measurements of Growth and Welfare for Policy Analysis
Measuring development, growth and welfare is an important issue in normative and positive economics.The issue is more critical in developing economies where a good statistical indicator of income, livingstandard or poverty is crucial for decision-makers in corporate, government, non-government andinternational organizations in their for-profit or non-profit plans to promote business and trade, ...
متن کاملAn EOQ model for non-instantaneous deteriorating items with two levels of storage under trade credit policy
A deterministic inventory model with two levels of storage (own warehouse and rented warehouse) with non-instantaneous deteriorating items is studied. The supplier offers the retailer a trade credit period to settle the amount. Different scenarios based on the deterioration and the trade credit period have been considered. In this article, we have framed two models considering single warehouse ...
متن کاملتعیین مالیات زیستمحیطی بهینه در الگوی رشد تعمیمیافته با وجود انتقال تکنولوژی پاک و کیفیت محیطزیست: نمونۀ اقتصاد ایران
This study aims at determining the optimal environmental tax policy in the context of a dynamic model. For this purpose, clean technology diffusion was added to the AK growth model and the theoretical model has been generalized to the open economy. The main feature of the economy is creating pollution in the process of economic growth and its negative impact on social welfare. The diffusion...
متن کاملذخیره در منابع من
با ذخیره ی این منبع در منابع من، دسترسی به آن را برای استفاده های بعدی آسان تر کنید
عنوان ژورنال:
دوره شماره
صفحات -
تاریخ انتشار 2002